Shica and Sunna
pray in Musa al-Kadhim Mosque |
Perhaps in no other country of the Middle East has the issue
of national reconciliation (Arabic: al-musaliha
al-wataniya; Kurdish: asht boonaway nishtimani) been so central to the national
political discourse as in Iraq. A true
policy of national reconciliation would constitute an important nail in the
terrorist coffin. Offering all Iraq's religious sects and ethniocities a place in the political system would be a sure bet to promote stability and undercut the allure of terrorist groups.
Why, then, has national reconciliation been so elusive in Iraq when virtually all analysts - Arab, Kurdish and Western – realize that it constitutes the key to ending sectarian-based violence and bringing political stability to the country?
Why, then, has national reconciliation been so elusive in Iraq when virtually all analysts - Arab, Kurdish and Western – realize that it constitutes the key to ending sectarian-based violence and bringing political stability to the country?
Bomb blast kills 66 in Baghdad - the cost of lack of national reconciliation |
Part 2 (to follow) will analyze the elements which are
needed to jump start the process of developing a national reconciliation
strategy in Iraq. This post will not
only examine possible changes in the future dynamics of Iraqi politics but
suggest elements of a national reconciliation policy which might actually lead
to meaningful political change.
To begin, why has there been no serious effort at national
reconciliation? The answer which is
often given is the lack of trust among the politicians who comprise Iraq’s
admittedly dysfunctional political elite.
That lack of trust, it is argued, is ingrained in Iraqi political
culture as a result of 35 years of Bacth Party rule (1968-2003).
The logic of this argument implies that considerable time must past before the different sects and ethnic groups, which
comprise the factions of Iraq’s political class, can come together and settle
their differences. What this argument accomplishes
is to take politicians “off the hook,” namely it provides an excuse as to why
they don’t need to address this critical issue.
National reconciliation is not on the agenda because everyone must wait
many years, if not generations, until the trust required to implement it is established.
Barzani meets Saddam in Baghdad |
Fearing that his Kurdish Democratic Party (KDP) and its Pesh Merga militia
would be defeated by the Pesh forces of the rival Patriotic Union of Kurdistan (PUK)
in the Kurdish Civil War, Barzani had no compunction in calling Saddam to come his
rescue. A result of Saddam's sending Republican Guard units to defend the KDP was the capture and execution of 700 PUK pesh merga and over 200 members of the opposition to the Bacthist regime and the arrest of 2500 more.
Barzani meeting Saddam's intelligence chief in Arbil, Aug 1996 |
Saddam 's Republican Guards in front of Kurdish parliament, 1996 |
Nor did Saddam and Masoud demonstrate any lack of trust
during the period of the severe UN sanctions regime which was imposed after the
1991 Gulf War as both worked together to smuggle oil out of Iraq in
contravention of the sanctions. In these
two instances, power and financial incentives clearly trumped ethnic distrust.
Victims of Halabja, Mar 1988 |
In explaining why there has been no national reconciliation
in Iraq – more than 13 years after the toppling of Saddam – a much more cogent
argument is not that politicians don’t trust one another. Rather the
key driver or independent variable is the desire of political elites to
accumulate power and wealth.
The lack of trust is not what prevents the Iraqi political
class from coming to terms with national reconciliation. While Nuri al-Maliki was prime minister, from
2006 t0 2014, he was often asked about national reconciliation and why it
wasn’t a policy priority. He
consistently replied that what Iraq needed was the “rule of law” (siyadat al-qanun), not national
reconciliation. In other words, in his
view national reconciliation was unimportant.
What Iraqis really needed was security. Of course, while Maliki was
prime minister, Iraq neither achieved the rule of law nor national
reconciliation.
Almost the entire Iraqi political elite is focused on narrow
political goals related their own self-interest. Of course, self-interest is a core motivation
of all politicians. However, we can cite the exceptions of morally motivated
actors such as Abraham Lincoln, Sojourner Truth, Harriet Tubman, Eleanor Roosevelt, Mahatma Gandhi, Martin Luther King, Jr., Nelson
Mandala and the Dali Lama, just to offer a few prominent examples.
But all politicians, if they are not to bring devastation
and destruction to their respective nation-states, and are to maintain at least
a modicum of legitimacy in the eyes of their constituents, must incorporate
some civic virtue into their political behavior. In other words, they must at least give lip
service to civic virtue and engage in a limited number of acts which they can
point to as indicating a larger commitment to their community.
In Iraq, there is a core contradiction between two
centrifugal forces, which have produced both a cooperative sum and zero sum game simultaneously. On the one hand, the political class wants to
control Iraq’s core asset, namely its oil wealth. This interest encourages the main Shici
Arab and Kurdish political elites to strive to maintain cooperative relations
in an effort to work out a mutually advantageous agreement on the production
and distribution of oil and the wealth from its sale in the world market.
On the other hand, the two elites which have dominated post-2003
Iraqi politics, the main Arab Shica parties – the Dacwa
Party, the Iraqi National Alliance and the Sadrists - and the two dominant
Kurdish parties – the Kurdish Democratic Party (KDP) and the Patriotic Union of
Kurdistan (PUK) - are most concerned to control their own respective spheres of
influence which are territorially based.
For the Shici political elite, this area encompasses Baghdad,
south central and southern Iraq, while for the Kurdish political elite, it includes
the 3 Kurdish majority provinces which comprise the KRG.
The tension between an instrumental support for federalism and
a desire to retreat into a “political comfort zone” produces an emphasis on vertical sociopolitical identities and an extreme aversion to horizontal identities. This explains why political elites are so
hostile to civil society organizations, youth groups, women’s organizations,
professional associations and labor unions, all of which seek to transcend
ethno-sectarian boundaries.
It also explains why the Iraqi political elite's desire to maximize power and wealth
through the exploitation of sectarian identities produces an inherently
authoritarian politics. Sectarian
entrepreneurship is incompatible with values of tolerance, political pluralism,
and cultural diversity, let alone expansive political participation
As the struggle of power between Arab and Kurdish elites has
intensified, each wing of Iraq’s political elite has decided to up the political
ante. Here the cooperative sum game, based primarily on mutually benefiting from oil wealth, competes with a zero-sum game where for one faction to win, the other must lose. This move was primarily motivated by the
inability of each elite to cover the massive corruption required to keep their
“political machines” functional.
The seizure of Mosul in 2014 raised the costs of military
intervention against Da’ish for both elites, but especially the Kurds who faced
a frontal attack on Arbil in July 2014, The fierce attack was only thwarted through intensive US
air strikes. The drop in oil prices has
further undermined the ability of either political elite to sustain the massive
corruption upon which it depends to retain the allegiance of countless minions
and to purchase the loyalty of its supporters. Indeed, when I was last in Iraq, I was told that as much as 80% of the national budget goes to the support corruption.
In Arab Iraq, but especially in the KRG, the displacement of
large numbers of Syrians and Iraqis has created additional logistical and
economic problems. The KRG’s population has
risen by 30% since the Da’ish seized Mosul while its ability to physically
accommodate this increased population, and economically support it, has decreased
dramatically with the steep drop in the price of oil.
Iraq Army 42nd Infantry Division |
In the short term, the key question raised by the liberation
of areas formerly held by the Da'ish in northwestern Iraq is rebuilding and caring
for displaced persons. In the long term,
the critical question which must be answered is who will rule the liberated
areas. Will it be Sunni Arab residents, and residents of other ethnic groups,
through their locally elected representatives, or will forces from outside these
regions, seek to remain in control.
In summary, the effort to avoid implementing national
reconciliation policies represents a threat to both wings of the Iraqi political
elite, (Shici) Arab and Kurdish. Their interest is not in promoting national reconciliation but in maintaining asnd institutionalizing an “ethno-sectarian
equilibrium.” However, the conquest of Sunni Arab areas creates tensions
because Kurdish forces have attempted to claim parts of these areas to be
integrated into the KRG (the so-called “disputed areas”).
At the same time, the collapse of oil prices, and the consequent reduced access to large sums of money to “grease the wheels” of the massive patronage systems
in Baghdad and Arbil, has presented who Sarah Chayes calls the “thieves of state”
with a huge problem. The promotion of
sectarian identities b y the Iraqi political elite in an effort to solidify vertical political identities increasingly faces serious challenges.
Iraqi workers and CSOs demonstrate for better wages and state services |
Ironically, the seizure of Mosul was not greeted with as
much concern as would have been expected by sectarian Shici parties
in Baghdad. For Nuri al-Maliki and
his cronies, the absence of Mosul and much of al-Anbar and Ninawa provinces from Iraqi politics meant
that Iraq’s Arab Sunni elite was now without a social base and thus had lost much
of its power.
Had the Da’ish not attempted to press its luck with an
attack on Arbil, in which KDP Pesh Merga forces performed very poorly and were
only rescued by US air attacks, an equilibrium might have become
institutionalized, with the Da’ish being allowed to exist by both wings of the Iraqi
political elite as long as it kept the threat level low and did not seek to move
to the south towards Baghdad or to the northeast towards Arbil and the KRG.
However, the near bankruptcy of the KRG and the refusal of
Masoud Barzani to relinquish the presidency of the KRG, despite having exceeded
his constitutionally defined term limit, has led for calls for Arab politicians
to act as intermediaries among the competing political factions in the KRG,
namely the KDP, PUK, the reformist Gorran (Change) Party and the Islamists. Once again, the issue of trust falls by the
wayside, and does not preclude inter-elite cooperation, when serious power or economic
interests are at stake.
There are at present a number of incentives to modify, if not
eliminate, the “political economy of corruption” in Iraq. First, a meaningful national reconciliation program
would incentivize Iraq’s Sunni Arab community to rejoin the political game and
de-incentivize them to turn to the so-called Islamic State and other terrorist
groups to meet their social and economic needs.
Greater cooperation between Iraq’s Shica
and Sunni Arab
communities would diminish the number of bombings and terrorist attacks in Baghdad
and Diyala Province which increased after the Da’ish was defeated and lost the
city of Ramadi, the capital of al-Anbar Province. Further, the costs of supplying Iraq’s armed
forces would decline as would the power of the Shica militias – the Popular
Mobilization Units (al-Hashid al-Shacbi)
- which present a threat to the power of
the Baghdad Shica elite.
Kurdish women who suffered from Anfal campaign visit Basra |
National reconciliation would thus meet the economic needs of both the
Arab and Kurdish wings of Iraq’s political elite by reducing the costs to each
in an economy which is experiencing serious downturns which, in turn, threatens
new forms of unrest, namely unrest based in economic discontent.
Former PM Nuri al-Maliki |
However rational the Iraqi political
elite views its behavior in promoting vertical sociopolitical identities, how long can they juggle an economic downturn with such behavior? Once these identities
begin to rupture, and groups with horizontally based interests begin to acquire
more power – a natural by-product of the national reconciliation process, the political elite - both Arab and Kurdish - will find its ability to maintain its iron grip of politics ever more difficult.
The ability of the Iraqi political elite to initiate a
comprehensive national reconciliation process would sound the death knell for
terrorism in Iraq. Terrorist organizations
like Abu Muscab al-Zarqawi’s al-Qacida
in the Land of the Two Rivers, and Abu Bakr al-Baghdadi’s so-called Islamic State would find little support
in Iraq if all political factions, sects and ethnic groups felt that had a seat
at the national political table.
How the US and exogenous forces might help promote national reconciliation in Iraq is the topic of my next post
How the US and exogenous forces might help promote national reconciliation in Iraq is the topic of my next post
No comments:
Post a Comment